Monday, September 30, 2013
Information Organization
I'm taking a class in the Information School this semester called Information Organization and Retrieval. It's about the intersection of computer science, library science, business information management, and database management. It provides a framework that unifies all those seemingly disparate disciplines. I find it to be extremely relevant right now, especially as I'm implementing a web app myself. Oroeco has to handle customer data as well as science data. We also then "create" new data that is tailored for the customer. Many decisions for how to organize the information are more about what makes sense conceptually than technically. Professor Robert Glushko argues that computer scientists could learn a lot from library science and vice versa.
This is a link to the syllabus.
http://blogs.ischool.berkeley.edu/i202f13/schedule/
Professor Glushko wrote a book The Discipline of Organizing
Labels:
data,
information organization,
information theory
Saturday, September 21, 2013
Impact Investing and Social Entrepreneurship
Two weeks ago I went to the SOCAP (Social Capital Markets) conference, an annual event hosted by Impact Hub Bay Area, which runs coworking spaces for social entrepreneurs.
The conference was at the Marina, a neighborhood along the northern coast of the peninsula. There was a really nice view of the Golden Gate Bridge and the mountains behind it.
The aim of SOCAP is to foster and promote
Many businesses have some negative externalities, such as making some workers obsolete. Even if this is "efficient" because overall welfare is increased, some people will be winning a lot while others unequivocally lose. This could be prevented by having the winners compensate the losers, but in real life, there's no good mechanism for doing this. One because it's hard to attribute one person's loss with another person's winnings. But also because the % of winnings people might need to give up may be high and not many people would willingly give up that much. If the winners are systematically undercompensating losers, things like neighborhood degradation could count as negative externalities. Traditional investing lead to these kinds of situations, where philanthropy plays the role of redistributing winnings. Then philanthropy is like the left hand handing out tiny band-aids while the right hand is periodically knocking people over. Here are some reasons why impact investing might lead to better outcomes, though.
1. It might be better instead to invest in activities that have smaller returns but don't have as many negative externalities or that redistribute winnings systematically as part of the operations of the business. In fact, economic theory also says that internalizing externalities would be more efficient. Therefore, the lower returns are only artifacts of different system boundaries and differences in accounting.
2. Projects that rely on traditional philanthropy get good at applying for grants to get more funding rather than getting good at making an impact. It is difficult to evaluate the effectiveness of a project within the context of traditional philanthropy. It would be better if indicators of project success were generated as a part of the operations of the project. If a project is able to make back 70% of the original grant, it could be a good indicator that the project is well-managed. Plus, that money can be reinvested into itself. The additional philanthropic dollar can be stretched much longer.
3. Since a dollar can be stretched in impact investing, not as much is needed to make an impact project sustainable. This means impact investing can be accessible to more people on the benefactor side. It also opens up a variety of new kinds of financial arrangements, making financing more accessible to more people on the recipient side.
4. Encouraging projects to become financially sustainable also imparts valuable knowledge about management and finance to communities that need to build up human resources. This is a very big and significant positive externality from impact investing that doesn't show up on the balance sheet.
The conference was at the Marina, a neighborhood along the northern coast of the peninsula. There was a really nice view of the Golden Gate Bridge and the mountains behind it.
The aim of SOCAP is to foster and promote
...a new form of capitalism is arising that recognizes our ability to direct the power and efficiency of market systems toward social impact.The conference brings together impact investors such as the Omidyar Network and social entrepreneurs such as myself. Impact investing is on the rise right now as an alternative to traditional philanthropy. Any arrangement where benefactors expect a less than 100% loss could be considered impact investing. They might get 50% of the money back or even make a return on the investment. According to standard economics and finance theory, this is less efficient than traditional investment, which maximizes returns, coupled with traditional philanthropy. This is because you should be able to get the most returns from traditional investing and thus have more to give out.
Many businesses have some negative externalities, such as making some workers obsolete. Even if this is "efficient" because overall welfare is increased, some people will be winning a lot while others unequivocally lose. This could be prevented by having the winners compensate the losers, but in real life, there's no good mechanism for doing this. One because it's hard to attribute one person's loss with another person's winnings. But also because the % of winnings people might need to give up may be high and not many people would willingly give up that much. If the winners are systematically undercompensating losers, things like neighborhood degradation could count as negative externalities. Traditional investing lead to these kinds of situations, where philanthropy plays the role of redistributing winnings. Then philanthropy is like the left hand handing out tiny band-aids while the right hand is periodically knocking people over. Here are some reasons why impact investing might lead to better outcomes, though.
1. It might be better instead to invest in activities that have smaller returns but don't have as many negative externalities or that redistribute winnings systematically as part of the operations of the business. In fact, economic theory also says that internalizing externalities would be more efficient. Therefore, the lower returns are only artifacts of different system boundaries and differences in accounting.
2. Projects that rely on traditional philanthropy get good at applying for grants to get more funding rather than getting good at making an impact. It is difficult to evaluate the effectiveness of a project within the context of traditional philanthropy. It would be better if indicators of project success were generated as a part of the operations of the project. If a project is able to make back 70% of the original grant, it could be a good indicator that the project is well-managed. Plus, that money can be reinvested into itself. The additional philanthropic dollar can be stretched much longer.
3. Since a dollar can be stretched in impact investing, not as much is needed to make an impact project sustainable. This means impact investing can be accessible to more people on the benefactor side. It also opens up a variety of new kinds of financial arrangements, making financing more accessible to more people on the recipient side.
4. Encouraging projects to become financially sustainable also imparts valuable knowledge about management and finance to communities that need to build up human resources. This is a very big and significant positive externality from impact investing that doesn't show up on the balance sheet.
Labels:
business,
investment,
social entrepreneurship
Tuesday, September 10, 2013
Early Signs From 2005
American RadioWorks did a series of shows called Reports from a Warming Planet.
The reports are from the work of a class taught by John Harte at ERG and environmental journalist Sandy Tolan. For most people, these anecdotes are probably much more persuasive than any scientific evidence that global warming is really happening and that it is a problem.
The reports are from the work of a class taught by John Harte at ERG and environmental journalist Sandy Tolan. For most people, these anecdotes are probably much more persuasive than any scientific evidence that global warming is really happening and that it is a problem.
Monday, September 9, 2013
Nuances About Economics
Ronald Coase was a famous economist who died recently. He came up with the Coase Theorem, which is the concept that initial allocation of an externality or good doesn't matter if there are no transaction costs (a big 'if'). In fact Coase himself acknowledges that in real economic situations, transaction costs are almost never low enough for the initial allocation not to matter. Nuances in economics are typically lost in politics. He's frequently cited by the right wing as being against governmental regulation and pro market solutions for environmental problems.
Severin Borenstein, a professor in the Haas Business School at UC Berkeley sets the record straight.
http://energyathaas.wordpress.com/2013/09/09/learning-and-forgetting-the-wisdom-of-coase/
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)